The Dispossession of the Peasantry (ص 138)

غرض

عنوان
The Dispossession of the Peasantry (ص 138)
المحتوى
122
and “in some relation to the net annual yield.”* It was a fixed tax estimated to be
about 10 percent of the net yield through 1942-1943. As a war measure, the rates
were doubled twice, except for citrus, in 1943-1944 and 1944-1945. Although it
was an improvement on the tithe, which was a tax on the gross yield and thus
taxed the costs of production, the Rural Property Tax had three main
shortcomings. First, the cost of production, which was assumed to be two thirds of
the gross yield, did not take in consideration the variation in cost in different
villages.** This across-the-board approach was obviously unfavorable to those
peasants who had costs higher than the estimated two thirds of the gross yield.
Second, this fixed rate did not take into account the variations in annual yields that
were susceptible to disease and an unpredictable amount of rainfall, especially in
the case of dry-farming crops. The Rural Property Tax, unlike the Urban Property
Tax, was based on presumed rather than an assessed return. Third, unlike the
Ottoman law, which allowed for land to lay fallow for three years, the new Rural
Property Tax was, true to its name, a tax on land when it was not planted.
At any rate, and in spite of these shortcomings, the new tax, in itself, was
an improvement on the tithe and werko. Nonetheless, as will be illustrated below,
the new tax was late in coming for the many peasants who lost their land before
1935 as a result of a combination of the “scissors crisis,” the tax burden, and
*“Ibid., 250.
Ibid., 253-4.
*“Abcarius, “Fiscal System,” 524.
Reproduced with permission of the copyright owner. Further reproduction prohibited without permission.
تاريخ
٢٠٠٦
المنشئ
Riyad Mousa

Contribute

A template with fields is required to edit this resource. Ask the administrator for more information.

Not viewed