Peasant Agriculture (ص 3)

غرض

عنوان
Peasant Agriculture (ص 3)
المحتوى
A principal driver of conflicts over land and resources in the early 21* century is the systemic agrarian
crisis facing peasants in Asia, Africa and Latin America. The global agrarian crisis has been driven by
world market prices for farm products being consistently lower than the local costs of producing farm
products, resulting in increased debt, as well as climate change (Akram-Lodhi 2018). The crisis has
meant that for many an exclusive emphasis on farming is not an adequate survival strategy because it
does not produce a rudimentarily secure livelihood (Bernstein 2009, World Bank 2007). It is now more
common for rural livelihoods to be constructed from a plethora of fragmentary and insecure sources: petty
commodity production in farming, to be sure; but also the sale of temporary and casualized waged labour,
both on and off-farm; as well as petty commodity handicraft manufacture, petty merchant trading, and the
provision of petty services. The relationship of peasants to product and labour markets has also changed:
while markets continue to be structured by the operation of personalized sets of patron-client relations, and
are thus bearers of power and privilege, their importance to petty commodity producer survival strategies
has increased. With rural livelihoods in the 21" century being constructed on such a vulnerable terrain,
there are now three dominant approaches to understanding the part of peasants in contemporary capitalism.
The first approach is that of Henry Bernstein, who says that ‘much is obscured by characterizing social
formations in the South today as peasant societies, or contemporary classes of petty-commodity producing
small farmers as peasants’ (Bernstein 2009, 249). For Bernstein, it is now far more useful to premise
analytical work upon ‘classes of labour', which comprise those that depend directly and indirectly on the
sale of their labour power for their own reproduction; in Bernstein's reading, petty farming should now be
seen as an indirect sale of labour power to capital. The second approach is that of Jan Douwe van der
Ploeg, who argues that smallholder farmers around the world have the capacity to remove themselves from
being “directly governed” by capitalist markets. Instead, they can use commodity and noncommodity
flows and circuits (van der Ploeg 2013: 72) to establish a range of “ordering principles” that reflect a set of
interacting “balances” between work and consumption, between drudgery and utility, between production
and reproduction, between scale and intensity, between internal and external resources, between autonomy
and dependence, and between people and living nature. The active capacity of peasant farm families to
engage in the "skilful coordination" (van der Ploeg 2013: 69) of these commodity and noncommodity
balances means that not only does the peasantry persist but indeed new peasantries are being created that
actively resist the encroachment of capitalist social relations of production into their livelihoods (van der
Ploeg 2013: Ch. 1). The third approach are those that see the continuing salience of the “agrarian
question”: the terms and conditions whereby capital is or is not transforming farming and agricultural
production systems. Capital transforms farming by enforcing market imperatives on peasants once their
products become produced for the purpose of sale rather than own-use. Market imperatives are the need in
commodity economies that commodities be sold if the enterprise is to survive, and this requires being
competitive. Competitiveness gives rise to the continual need for productivity improvements, cost
reductions, and to tendencies toward increases in the size and scale of the farm for those producers that are
able to successfully engage in commodity production. In doing so market imperatives facilitate the
emergence of capitalist relations of production, in which the means of production fall under the control of
a socially-dominant hegemonic class, labour is “free” from significant shares of the means of production
and free to sell its capacity to work, and the purpose of commodity production is the seeking of profit
(Akram-Lodhi and Kay 2010a). However, it is empirically clear that this picture of a capitalist agrarian
transition does not reflect the exigences facing contemporary peasant production and reproduction, in
which capitalist development has proceeded without the wholesale transformation of peasant social
organization and created a set of “historical puzzles” that reflect
substantive diversity, rooted in globally-embedded, historically-informed and country-specific
trajectories of variation, which can cumulatively assist in understanding paths of agrarian
هو جزء من
Peasant Agriculture
تاريخ
2019-08-26
المنشئ
Haroon Akram-Lodhi
مجموعات العناصر
Generated Pages Set

Contribute

A template with fields is required to edit this resource. Ask the administrator for more information.

Position: 9726 (5 views)